Stanford Institute
for Economic Policy Research, Policy
Brief, June 2004.
In mid-2003, press reports began to surface of a project within the
Defense Advanced Research Projects Agency (DARPA) to establish a Policy
Analysis Market. The DARPA proposal was a natural application of an emerging
body of economic research suggesting that markets aggregate information
efficiently, and that the profit motive provides powerful incentives for
traders to discover new sources of information. The implicationif markets
assess risk efficientlyis that market prices provide useful indicators of the
likelihood of specific events. And beyond usual financial markets, perhaps
these prediction markets can be used to assess the likelihood of a wide range
of risks, including geopolitical events.
Sensationalist headlines dubbed the proposed DARPA markets Terrorism Futures, and the resulting furor forced the administration
to abandon the project and led to pressure for the resignation of DARPA
department head John Poindexter.
Ironically, the aftermath of this episode provided a vivid illustration
of the power of markets to provide information about probabilities of future
events. An offshore betting exchange, TradeSports.com, listed a new security
that paid $100 if Poindexter were ousted by the end of August 2003. Early
trading suggested a likelihood of resignation by the end of August of 40
percent, and price fluctuations reflected ongoing news developments. Around
lunchtime on July 31, reports started citing credible Pentagon insiders who
claimed knowledge of an impending resignation. Within minutes
of this news first surfacing (and hours before it became widely known), the
price spiked to around $80. These initial reports left the date of
Poindexters proposed departure uncertain, which explains the remaining risk.
As August dragged on, the price slowly fell back toward $50. On August 12,
Poindexter issued a letter of resignation suggesting that he would resign on
August 29. On the 12th, the market rose sharply, closing at a price of $96.
This anecdote describes a newand emergingform of financial markets called prediction markets. These markets are similar to existing financial markets in that participants trade in contracts whose payoffs depend on future events, but they differ in that there are likely very few traders with an obvious desire to use these markets to transfer their risk exposure (in the case above, few beyond the Poindexter family). Indeed, the main purpose of these securities is that the priceusually a by-product of financial tradingreveals market expectations of the likelihood of an event occurring.
Much of the enthusiasm for
prediction markets derives from the efficient markets hypothesis. In a truly
efficient prediction market, the market price will be the best predictor of
likelihood of an event occurring, and no combination of available information
can be used to improve on the market-generated forecasts. While this hypothesis
has typically been applied to standard financial contracts, our research
suggests that it (roughly) applies to prediction markets focusing on outcomes
from the box office success of specific movies, to the probability of war in
Empirically, these markets have been just as much of a success as theory predicts. Want to figure out the likely winning margin on the next Stanford game? Research on sports betting suggests that the Vegas line is the place to look. Want to predict next months non-farm payrolls numbers? Forget the analyststake a look at the latest trading at www.economicderivatives.com. What about the future federal funds rate? Try the CBOE. Or the opening box office take of Spider-Man 2? You can bet that the latest prices on the Hollywood Stock Exchange (www.hsx.com) will be a useful guide. Or for predicting a range of events from the Kobe Bryant trial to the next retirement from the Supreme Court, try www.intrade.com. New firms, including www.newsfutures.com, are even setting up trading markets within firms, so that management can have access to the widely dispersed information that may exist within their companies about future sales, regulatory actions or likely product success.
Some of the best developed evidence
on the power of prediction markets comes from political markets set up by the
Interestingly, recent research by Koleman Strumpf and Paul Rhode suggests that the idea of using markets to price political risk is not that new after all. Indeed, election betting predates polling. Press reports of elections around the turn of the century focused on informal betting markets on Wall Street to take the pulse of presidential campaigns. And historical research confirms the predictive accuracy of these Wall Street betting markets. Indeed, as early as 1924, the New York Times, citing the old axiom in the financial district that Wall Street betting odds are never wrong, understood that the efficient markets hypothesis was equally as powerful in the political domain.
Of course, before relying on these
market prices, it is worth thinking about the possibility for manipulation.
While this is surely an issue, Strumpf and Rhode report that attempts by the
big party bosses to manipulate these betting markets usually failed and
resulted simply in party bosses losing money. More controlled experiments in the
While prediction is useful, the more important question is whether these markets can be used to guide decisions. I am willing to bet they are.
Figure 1 shows a salient example
relating stock market responses to ongoing equivocation about whether to invade
So what do these markets have to
say about Election 2004? My own favorite markets are run by www.intrade.com (also known as TradeSports), where so far over $3 million has changed hands. According
to the latest estimates (early June 2004), this election looks like an
extremely close race, with the punters betting that Bush has only a 57 percent
chance to hang onan extremely
low assessment for an incumbent president. Intrade
also has established novel markets on the Electoral College, state-by-state.
These markets suggest that
We also have been working with Intrade to create a novel set of contingent securities, which may have more direct implications for policymakers. For instance, we were interested in the extent to which market participants perceive President Bushs re-election prospects to being contingent on succeeding in the hunt for Osama Bin Laden. In early trading, a contract that pays $100 if Bush is re-elected and Osama captured by November was priced at around $20.80. Separate (unconditional) markets on the fate of Bin Laden suggested a 27 percent chance that Osama would be captured before the election. Combining these two facts suggests that if Osama is captured, the market believes Bush to have a 77 percent chance to win the election. Combining this finding with the fact that Bush is rated a 57 percent chance to win (overall), implies that if Osama remains at large, President Bushs chances of re-election fall to 50 percent. While this example is rather speculative, at the very least it is suggestive of new ways in which we might learn about market expectations of the likely effects of actionseven actions that are yet to occur.
The power of prediction markets derives from three simple forces. First, by forcing you to put your money where your mouth is, they yield truthful revelation of beliefs. Second, markets provide profit opportunities for those willing to gather new information that helps predict the future. And third, markets aggregate information dispersed across many traders.
Political risk is an important
issue for economists, policymakers in
Assistant Professor of Economics,
For further details, see Prediction Markets, by Justin
Wolfers and Eric Zitzewitz, Journal
of Economic Perspectives, Spring 2004 (SIEPR Discussion Paper #03-025), and
What Do Financial Markets Think of War in Iraq? (SIEPR Discussion Paper
#02-028).