
Economics,
Experiments and Psychology
By Justin Wolfers & Andrew Leigh
With the
announcement that the 2002 Nobel Prize in economics had been awarded to Daniel
Kahneman of Princeton University and Vernon Smith of George Mason University,
the Nobel Committee has finally acknowledged the force of one of the most
important forces in economics: psychology.
Economics has long been criticized for losing touch with reality.
The key to much of our modern theory is an abstract rational economic
man, an unfeeling but hyper-rational creature, who cares only about himself.
Indeed, the 1990s saw the term economic rationalist often used
pejoratively to describe the unfeeling technocrats who were perceived to
dominate university economics departments and Canberras halls of power. From
Michael Pusey to Bob Ellis, critics have tended to equate economic rationalism
with economic analysis.
But not all economics is rational.
Kahneman and Behavioural Economics
A new breed of behavioural economists, led by Professor Kahneman, has sought to
bring insights from psychology in touch with economics. The method is simple, but radical. Rather than observe people in markets and find way to
rationalize their behaviour, these social scientists insist on close and careful
observation.
Originally trained as a psychologist (and indeed the first psychologist to win
the Nobel Prize in economics), Professor Kahneman set about testing various
aspects of the rational paradigm. In a series of experiments, he has
systematically examined how people make decisions when facing uncertainty. Much
of this research was conducted with Amos Tversky of Stanford University, who
almost certainly would have shared this prize if Nobels were awarded
posthumously.
Kahnemans findings were at odds of much of rational economics. For instance,
he found that people tend to give possible losses twice as much as weight as
gains. This can then lead people to
be sensitive to how a particular decision is framed.
In a famous experiment, doctors were found to be more likely to recommend
a particular treatment to combat a hypothetical disease outbreak if it is
described in terms of survival rates (gains) than mortality rates (losses).
People also make probability assessments that violate the basic laws of
probability. For instance, a
hypothetical Linda was described as a bright and outspoken philosophy
major interested in social issues. Experimental subjects assessed it more likely
that she was both a feminist and a bank teller, than that she was simply
a bank teller.
Kahneman argues that instead of actually making complex probability assessments,
we tend to use very simple rules-of-thumb. These heuristics are usually fairly
accurate, but sometimes lead us to make mistakes.
Just as game theory did in the 1970s, behavioural economics is revolutionising
economics today. Researchers following in Kahneman and Tverskys footsteps are
drawing on psychology to integrate notions of fairness, reciprocity,
self-control, emotions and identity into economics.
Smith and Experimental Economics
Vernon Smiths contribution is no less important.
A major barrier to the acceptance of Kahnemans ideas had been
reluctance among economists to accept any forms of experimental evidence,
arguing that while subjects tested in the lab may act irrationally, when it
comes to real market transactions involving high stakes, we are far less likely
to err. This methodological barrier
hindered the flow of ideas between the laboratory-based psychology, and
market-based economic analysis.
Smith has made laboratory experiments respectable within economics, and designed
fundamental methods to enhance their plausibility.
Rather than simply postulate that one type of market works better than another,
Smith has insisted on trialing both under controlled conditions.
For instance, economic theory had long suggested that most types of
auctions would yield the same final price.
Yet in his laboratory experiments, a standard open-cry auction,
with bids announced in increasing order, consistently yielded a higher result
than Dutch auctions, in which the auctioneer starts with a high price, and
keeps lowering it until a bidder is found.
Not surprisingly, this work is of intense interest to policymakers, and Smith
was consulted in the design of Australian energy markets. When the value of the
prize is high, even small differences in design in these markets can have
important economic impacts.
New research
Among US economists, behavioural economics has been more widely recognised at
the saltwater departments (those in the coastal universities of Harvard,
MIT, and Berkeley) than the freshwater departments (those on the great
lakes, such as the Universities of Chicago and Minnesota). One critique from the
freshwater departments has been that the behaviouralists have been slow to show
that their psychology-based theories have important implications in the real
world.
Yet the research is beginning to emerge. A recent paper by James Choi, David
Laibson Brigitte Madrian, and Andrew Metrick has shown that framing has important
implications for saving patterns.
In a study of three major corporations, they found that when employees were
given the option of enrolling in a savings plan at the time of joining
the company, around three in ten did so. But when employees were given the
choice of opting out of the savings plan, the enrolment rate rose to
eight in ten. The most dramatic rise in savings came among employees who earned
least suggesting that simple changes can have dramatic effects on raising
the saving rate of the poorest.
Laibson has also been at the forefront of designing a model of intertemporal
choice known as hyperbolic discounting, which is rapidly finding its way
into other areas of economics. The insight behind
hyperbolic discounting is straightforward when faced with a choice between
$10 in 30 days, and $11 in 31 days, almost everyone takes the $11. But when the
choice is between $10 today and $11 tomorrow, some people will take the $10. The
tradeoff between today and tomorrow is surprisingly steep, and at odds with the
conventional models in economics that suggest the two alternatives are
essentially the same - although posed at different points in time and as
such, similar choices should be made.
One of the first studies to make use of hyperbolic discounting, by Stefano Della
Vigna and Ulrike Malmendier, young Assistant Professors at Berkeley and Stanford
respectively, has shown that gym-goers who purchase monthly or annual
memberships tend to attend so infrequently that they end up paying more per
visit than the casual rate.
On average, gym-goers in their study were $700 worse off than if they had gone
on a pay-per-use basis. Della Vigna and Malmendier conclude that this reflects
the fact that many gym users are overconfident at the outset about their ability
to sustain an exercise routine, but when faced with the actual decision, are
unwilling to suffer the short-term pain.
Finally, work by Jonathan Gruber and Sendhil Mullainathan (both at MIT) shows
that taxes can make us happier in the long run; the focus of their study was the
cigarette tax.
If smokers are hyperbolic discounters, they will actually be happier if society
imposes limits on their ability to make bad decisions in the short-run. Unlike
rational addiction models, the hyperbolic model suggests that smokers
value self-control devices, of which taxes may be one. Indeed, when the authors
test this hypothesis against data from Canada and the United States, they
evidence that levels of self-reported happiness are higher among smokers in
states and provinces with higher cigarette taxes.
Until now, experimental economics and behavioural economics have been closely
linked, but their very success may be leading to divergent paths. As economists have started to understand that the strong
rationality assumptions underlying their theoretical models may be violated,
they have shown an increasing penchant for testing their ideas in the
laboratory. Equally, behavioural economists are starting to leave the
laboratory, and look to explain a variety of problems in the world around us.
Issues of saving behaviour, gym attendance, and smoking taxes are likely only
the beginning. Thanks to this years Nobel laureates, the scope of this
research is likely to only expand.
Dr Justin Wolfers is an Assistant Professor of
Economics at Stanford Business School. Andrew
Leigh is a Ph.D. student at Harvards John F. Kennedy School of Government.